Standing Stone: reasons for adopting a 'just price' for housing
We live in a late capitalist society in which
democratic politicians have deliberately stoked a speculative bubble
in housing prices, because most voters are property owners and
spiralling house prices mean that those who are already on the
housing ladder feel richer. The consequence of this is that, over the
country as a whole, house prices are already beyond the reach of many
folk on ordinary wages. Along the Solway coast, the pretty villages
have a price premium because they are attractive and pleasant places
to live, but local wages are depressed. This means that folk working
in the local economy cannot buy houses locally – unless they have
inherited wealth.
So begins a process of clearance which is just as
socially corrosive as the clearances of the eighteenth century, when
the landowners enclosed land which had traditionally been common. The
reaction, then, here in Galloway, was of a violent revolt by the
country folk, throwing down the walls of the new enclosures and
burning barns. Now, here in Auchencairn, I think the Caldows and
Helen Sankey are the only people born in the village who still live
on the main street (Geordie Milligan lives on Spout Row). Every other
house is owned by incomers, and the native population has been
effectively cleared across the burn into the bantustan of social
housing. We have a very nearly complete ethnic segregation, with
those who live in the old village now overwhelmingly rich and
English, and the Crescent overwhelmingly poor and Scots.
It wasn't always like this. The three houses
across the street for me, when last sold in the 1950s, were bought
for less than two hundred and fifty pounds for all three. When I
bought my first flat in the village, I paid four thousand pounds.
Now, the only property for sale in the village under a hundred
thousand pounds is Monty's flat – which is tiny.
Unless ordinary people without inherited wealth
are able to afford to own houses in this area on wages earned in this
area, the social dislocation and, effectively, ethnic cleansing is
only going to get worse. Ultimately, that must lead to unrest.
Applying this to Standing Stone
None of this is the fault of anyone in the
Standing Stone project. It is a consequence of political and economic
forces which are far bigger than us.
However, if we do get planning permission to build
new dwellings on the Standing Stone site, the market value of those
dwellings when they are complete will be very much greater than what
they cost to build. If we don't cap the resale price, then we are
effectively giving one another a speculators' charter, and we risk
the site rapidly developing into yet another rich incomers' enclave.
We risk this both because the speculative opportunity will suck in
spivs, and because your actual people – the sort of folk we would
choose to live among, that we think in developing the idea that we
are choosing to live among – simply won't be able to afford to buy
into it.
People have objected – very reasonably – that
they need to be able to get their investment out again. And it is
true that if the housing market continues to spiral madly out of
control, then if we put a cap on resale prices of dwellings at
Standing Stone then people may not be able to leave, because the
capped price will not realise enough money to buy a replacement
property on the open market. These are real and reasonable issues.
The just price
Clearly if we are to derive a formula for a 'just
price' for a dwelling, that formula needs to represent the investment
which has been put in – including investment as 'sweat equity', our
own labour which we've expended in creating the dwelling.
Furthermore, we need to notionally detach the
value of the land from the value of the dwelling. The 'croft' part of
the holding – without planning permission – has a value as
agricultural land. So the capped value of a holding, if we choose to
adopt a 'just price' cap, is the market value of the agricultural
land plus the capped value of the dwelling, and (irrespective of what
DGSHT's policy says) clearly the 'just price' cannot be less than the
total amount reasonably invested. If Ruth has invested
a sum in the farmhouse, then she must be able to realise at least
that sum if at some time in the future she needs to sell. To expect
her to accept less is just unreasonable.
But at the other end of the scale I'm expecting to
spend less than £40,000 cash (and a lot of work) on structure. My
dwelling, at the end of that, will have one bedroom, rather than the
three or four that the farmhouse has, but as a modern designer
structure with a nice view it's open market value isn't going to be a
lot less. If I'm spending £55,000 on ten acres of land, then the
pro-rata cost of the half-acre of that which forms the curtilage of
the dwelling is about £2,500. For simplicity say I spend £7,500 on
design fees and contractors, and value six months of my full-time
equivalent labour at £10,000, then the investment cost of my
dwelling is
Land:
|
£2,500
|
Fees and contractors
|
£7,500
|
Sweat equity
|
£10,000
|
Structure
|
£40,000
|
Total
|
£60,000
|
Should I be allowed to sell this dwelling which
has cost me £60,000 for £120,000? Why? What justifies me making
such a speculative profit?
The affordable price
The average annual wage in Dumfries and Galloway
is around £20,000. This means that the cost price of my one bedroom
dwelling is three times the income of a single wage earner – a
multiplier which is certainly acceptable to mortgage lenders.
Actually, DGSCHT consider a multiplier of 3.5 times average annual
wage to be reasonable. And on a two bedroom dwelling, that's 3.5
times not the income of one wage earner, but the income of 1.5 wage
earners – a household with one person working full time and one
person working part time. So the affordable price of my one-bedroom
dwelling would be £75,000, and the affordable price of a two or
three bedroom dwelling would be £105,000.
Now, OK, in aiming for a £40,000 structure cost
I'm aiming to build a structure which is affordable to me, so it has
to be 'affordable' – I'm too old to take on new debt. But a cost of
£1,200 per square metre seems a commonly quoted value these days, so
(allowing the same figures for land value of the curtilage and for
fees as in my example) you have £95,000 to spend on structure of two
to three bedrooms (including sweat equity), which builds you 80
square metres of reasonable quality structure, which is equivalent to
six rooms each 12 foot by 12 foot.
Thus it seems to me that it is possible to build
new dwellings on the site such that the cost is lower than the
'affordable price'. Furthermore, knowing what I do of the group, all
of us are going to have to build dwellings which cost less than the
'affordable price', simply because none of us are rich.
The just price revisited
This doesn't solve the Ruth conundrum, of course,
because she's having to buy at full market rate and cannot be
expected to take a hit to sell at an 'affordable price'.
So we need a formula which I think is something
like this:
value of the land
part of the holding
plus reasonable
investment cost of dwelling
plus 2% per
annum compound interest on the reasonable investment cost of the
dwelling
where:
value of the land
is the agricultural value of the land as assessed by a qualified
surveyor appointed by the Company
reasonable
investment cost is for new builds and for the byre units an
agreed multiple on the internal area of the dwelling in square
metres, I'd suggest £1,200; for the existing dwelling, the price
actually paid (including essential renovations).
This gives us a 'just price' which for all new
units is likely to be lower than or equal to the 'affordable price'
as seen by DGSCHT.
Non-idealistic argument for a just price formula
The arguments I advanced at the head of this
document for a just price for housing are idealistic; they represent
a rejection of the market in favour of enhancing social cohesion and
abstract 'fairness'. I believe that most of us do have a degree of
idealism, but I acknowledge that the exact degree varies.
However, bear in mind that getting planning
permission for ten new dwellings on this site is a very big ask. It
is precisely the 'sporadic development in the countryside' that the
council has policy to prevent. We're going to have to do a lot of
special pleading and special argument. If we fail to get planning
permission, we're most of us going to have had a significant share of
all our capital tied up for at least two years in land, with nowhere
to live. And although it's probable that if it all goes pear shaped
we can resell the land for the money invested, that isn't guaranteed.
So we need all the help we can get. We can get a
certain amount of political if we're able to play the 'green' card,
the 'low impact' card (but I'm not certain I can achieve low impact
in my budget, and I suspect other people may be the same; concrete is
cheap stuff). One card that we know we can play, though, is
'affordable housing'. And, we already know that if we play the
affordable housing card, we will get not insignificant help from
DGSCHT.
In summary, if we cap resale at an 'affordable'
value, we will be able to recover the investment made in dwellings
(provided we're don't built using solid gold taps and marble
staircases), and we will get significant support which will
significantly lower the risk involved in the project. That seems to
me a substantial win for very little actual cost.
No comments:
Post a Comment